Financial economics as a normal science: A critical approach from the perspective of Kuhn’s concept of paradigms and Lakatos’ scientific programmes
PDF (Język Polski)

Keywords

financial economics
paradigms
scientific research programmes
Kuhn
Lakatos
JEL: B26, G00, G30

How to Cite

Walasik, A. (2024). Financial economics as a normal science: A critical approach from the perspective of Kuhn’s concept of paradigms and Lakatos’ scientific programmes. Ruch Prawniczy, Ekonomiczny I Socjologiczny, 86(1), 133–147. https://doi.org/10.14746/rpeis.2024.86.1.08

Number of views: 82


Number of downloads: 73

Abstract

The study of monetary phenomena and processes taking place in the economy is of interest to a wide range of representatives of the academic community. Researchers who analyse the phenomena and processes in question, and who invest effort in this area, consider it to be scientific activity, and are of the view that they are conducting scientific research. Does financial economics therefore use an original set of ontological and epistemological assumptions? If so, what deserves to be recognized as a paradigm of financial economics? This article attempts to assess financial economics from the perspective of the philosophy of science. The answers to these questions will make it possible to isolate the essence of financial economics, thus defining its ontological boundaries, and to determine from the epistemological perspective whether there is a distinct method of financial economics. The article discusses financial economics from the perspective of the philosophy of science. In particular it follows Kuhn’s theoretical framework to identify and critically analyse paradigms of financial economics. The paper concludes that financial economics is a normal science, in the sense defined by Kuhn, as research arising from one or more scientific achievements of the past, which a given community of scientists currently accepts and treats as the foundation of its further practice. The paper indicates the fundamental works that constitute the hard core of financial economics in the sense of the assumptions of the scientific research programmes described by Lakatos.

https://doi.org/10.14746/rpeis.2024.86.1.08
PDF (Język Polski)

References

Blaug, M. (1975). Kuhn versus Lakatos, or paradigms versus research programmes in the history of economics. History of Political Economy, 7(4), 399–433. DOI: https://doi.org/10.1215/00182702-7-4-399

Blaug, M. (1980). The methodology of economics: Or how economists explain. Cambridge University Press.

Blaug, M. (1995). Metodologia ekonomii (B. Czarny i A. Molisak, tłum.). Wydawnictwo Naukowe PWN.

Brewer, D. E., i Michaelsen, J. B. (1965). The cost of capital, corporation finance, and the theory of investment: Comment. American Economic Review, 55(3), 516–524. https://www.jstor.org/stable/1814565

Buchanan, J. M. (1964). What should economists do? Southern Economic Journal, 30(3), 213–222. DOI: https://doi.org/10.2307/1055931

Buchanan, J. M. (1988). Contractarian political economy and constitutional interpretation. American Economic Review, 78(2), 135–139. https://www.jstor.org/stable/1818111

Buiter, W. (1989). Macroeconomic theory and stabilization policy. Manchester University Press. DOI: https://doi.org/10.3998/mpub.12220

Durand, D. (1959). The cost of capital, corporation finance, and the theory of investment: Comment. American Economic Review, 59(4), 639–654. https://www.jstor.org/stable/1812918

Encarnación, J. (1983). Positive time preference: A comment. Journal of Political Economy, 91(4), 706–708. https://www.jstor.org/stable/1831075 DOI: https://doi.org/10.1086/261173

Fama, E. F. (1970). Efficient capital markets: A review of theory and empirical work. Journal of Finance, 25(2), 383–417. DOI: https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1970.tb00518.x

Fama, E. F. (1991). Efficient capital markets: II. Journal of Finance, 46(5), 1575–1617. DOI: https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1991.tb04636.x

Fama, E. F. (1998). Market efficiency, long-term returns, and behavioral finance. Journal of Financial Economics, 49(3), 283–306. DOI: https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304-405X(98)00026-9

Frederick, S., Loewenstein, G., i O’Donoghue, T. (2002). Time discounting and time preference: A critical review. Journal of Economic Literature, 40(2), 351–401. https://www.jstor.org/stable/2698382 DOI: https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.40.2.351

Frydman, R., i Goldberg, M. D. (2013). Mechaniczne rynki a świat realny. Wahania cen aktywów, ryzyko i rola państwa (T. Krzyżanowski, tłum.). Wydawnictwo Krytyki Politycznej.

Galor, O., i Özak, Ö. (2016). The agricultural origins of time preference. American Economic Review, 106(10), 3064–3103. DOI: https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20150020

Gollier, C. (2001). The economics of risk and time. MIT Press. DOI: https://doi.org/10.7551/mitpress/2622.001.0001

Greenberg, E., Marshall, W. J., i Yawitz, J. B. (1978). The technology of risk and return. American Economic Review, 68(3), 241–251. https://www.jstor.org/stable/1805257

Hicks, J. R. (1939). Value and capital: An inquiry into some fundamental principles of economic theory. Clarendon Press.

Hicks, J. R. (1975). Wartość i kapitał. Studia nad kilkoma podstawowymi zagadnieniami w teorii ekonomii (J. Osiatyński, tłum.). Państwowe Wydawnictwo Naukowe.

Hirshleifer, J. (1970). Investment, interest, and capital. Prentince-Hall.

Homer, S., i Sylla, R. (2005). A history of interest rates (4th ed.). John Wiley & Sons.

Jensen, J. L. (1906). Sur les fonctions convexes et les inégalités entre les valeurs moyennes. Acta Mathematica, 30(1), 175–193. DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/BF02418571

Keenan, M. (1970). Models of equity valuation: The great serm bubble. Journal of Finance, 25(2), 243–273. DOI: https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1970.tb00505.x

Keynes, J. M. (1936). The general theory of employment interest and money. Macmillan and Co.

Keynes, J. M. (1956). Ogólna teoria zatrudnienia, procentu i pieniądza (M. Kalecki i S. Rączkowski, tłum.). Państwowe Wydawnictwo Naukowe.

Kuhn, T. S. (2001). Struktura rewolucji naukowych (H. Ostromęcka, tłum.). Fundacja Aletheia.

Kuhn, T. S. (2006). Przewrót kopernikański. Astronomia planetarna w dziejach myśli Zachodu (S. Amsterdamski, tłum., wyd. 2). Prószyński i S-ka.

Lakatos, I. (1995). Pisma z filozofii nauk empirycznych (W. Sady, tłum.). Wydawnictwo Naukowe PWN.

Lange, O. (1945). Price flexibility and employment. Principia Press.

Lange, O. (1973). Elastyczność cen i zatrudnienie. W: O. Lange, Dzieła: Tom 1. Kapitalizm. Polskie Wydawnictwo Ekonomiczne.

Lintner, J. (1965). The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investments in stock portfolios and capital budgets. Review of Economics and Statistics, 47(1), 13–37. DOI: https://doi.org/10.2307/1924119

Loewenstein, G., i Prelec, D. (1991). Negative time preference. American Economic Review, 81(2), 347–352. https://www.jstor.org/stable/2006883

Malkiel, B. G. (2003). The efficient market hypothesis and its critics. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(1), 59–82. DOI: https://doi.org/10.1257/089533003321164958

Marciano, A. (2009). Buchanan’s constitutional political economy: exchange vs. choice in economics and in politics. Constitutional Political Economy, 20(1), 42–56. DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-008-9048-2

Mayer, T. (1996). Prawda kontra precyzja w ekonomii (A. Szeworski, tłum.). Wydawnictwo Naukowe PWN.

Merton, R. C. (1997). Continuous-time finance. Blackwell.

Miller, M. H. (1988). The Modigliani-Miller propositions after thirty years. Journal of Economic Perspective, 2(4), 99–120. DOI: https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.2.4.99

Miller, M. H. (1991). Leverage. Journal of Finance, 46(2), 479–488. DOI: https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1991.tb02670.x

Mirowski, P. (1999). More heat than light: Economics as social physics, physics as nature’s economics. Cambridge University Press.

Modigliani, F., i Miller, M. H. (1958). The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment. American Economic Review, 48(3), 261–297. https://www.jstor.org/stable/1809766

Modigliani, F., i Miller, M. H. (1959). The cost of capital, corporation finance, and the theory of investment: Reply. American Economic Review, 49(4), 655–669. https://www.jstor.org/stable/1812919

Modigliani, F., i Miller, M. H. (1963). Corporate income taxes and the cost of capital: A correction. American Economic Review, 53(3), 433–443. https://www.jstor.org/stable/1809167

Modigliani, F., i Miller, M. H. (1965). The cost of capital, corporation finance, and the theory of investment: Reply. American Economic Review, 55(3), 524–527. https://www.jstor.org/stable/1814566

Mossin, J. (1966). Equilibrium in a capital asset market. Econometrica, 34(4), 768–783. DOI: https://doi.org/10.2307/1910098

Nickles, T. (2003). Normal science: from logic to case-based and model-based reasoning. W: T. Nickles (red.), Thomas Kuhn (s. 142–177). Cambridge University Press. DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511613975.008

Olson, M., i Bailey, M. J. (1981). Positive time preference. Journal of Political Economy, 89(1), 1–25. DOI: https://doi.org/10.1086/260947

Painlevé, P. (1960). The place of mathematical reasoning in economics. W: L. Sommer (red.), Essays in European economic thought (s. 120–132). D. Van Nostrand Company.

Rist, G. (2015). Urojenia ekonomii (Ś. F. Nowicki, tłum.). Instytut Wydawniczy Książka i Prasa.

Robbins, L. (1945). An essay on the nature and significance of economic science (2nd ed.). Macmillan.

Robbins, L. (1981). Economics and political economy. American Economic Review, 71(2), 1–10. https://www.jstor.org/stable/1815684

Robson, A. J., i Szentes, B. (2014). A biological theory of social discounting. American Economic Review, 104(11), 3481–3497. DOI: https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.104.11.3481

Ross, J. R. (1959). The cost of capital, corporation finance, and the theory of investment: Comment. American Economic Review, 49(4), 638–639. https://www.jstor.org/stable/1812917

Ross, S. A. (1977). The capital asset pricing model (CAPM), short-sale restrictions and related issues. Journal of Finance, 32(1), 177–183. DOI: https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1977.tb03251.x

Ross, S. A. (1978). The current status of the capital asset pricing model (CAPM). Journal of Finance, 33(3), 885–901. DOI: https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1978.tb02029.x

Samuelson, P. A. (1947). Foundations of economic analysis. Harvard University Press.

Schwartz, R. A. (1970). Efficient capital market: a review of theory and empirical work: Discussion. Journal of Finance, 25(2), 421–423. DOI: https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1970.tb00664.x

Sharpe, W. F. (1964, September). Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk. The Journal of Finance, 19(3), 425–442. DOI: https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1964.tb02865.x

Sharpe, W. F. (1970). Efficient capital markets: a review of theory and empirical work: Discussion. Journal of Finance, 25(2), 418–420. DOI: https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1970.tb00519.x

Sharpe, W. F. (1991). Capital asset prices with and without negative holdings. Journal of Finance, 46(2), 489–509. DOI: https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1991.tb02671.x

Shiller, R. J. (2003). From efficient markets theory to behavioral finance. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(1), 83–104. DOI: https://doi.org/10.1257/089533003321164967

Solow, R. M. (1985). Economic history and economics. American Economic Review, 75(2), 328–331.

Whitehead, A. N. (1929). Science and the modern world. Cambridge University Press.

Wittgenstein, L. (1997). Tractatus logico-philosophicus (B. Wolniewicz, tłum.). Wydawnictwo Naukowe PWN.

Zorde, K. (2004). Metafizyczne wątki w ekonomii. Wydawnictwo Naukowe PWN.